I. BRIEF HISTORY
From this criticism it appears that Choudhury tries to understand Ibn Khaldun as an intellectual who is separated from spirit of Islamic epistemology, something that actually may become perilous. This can be understood if the ideas in Ibn Khaldun’s work are not viewed in a unified concept. It is undenied that a large part of Ibn Khaldun’s writing in Muqaddima contains empirical explanation on contemporary phenomena that goes on around him in his age. It is because Ibn Khaldun’s career path walked in the midst of political situations, which contain dynamic intrigues and interests of different rulers. However, to place Ibn Khaldun as an intellectual who does not have any methodology that leads to Islamic epistemology is clearly a misconception. Furthermore, it should be noted that Choudhury‘s criticism is merely based on Muqaddima (translated by Franz Rosenthal), a book written by Ibn Khaldun as introduction to a planned bigger book called Kitab al-Ibar.
Abu Zaid Abdurrahman bin Muhammad bin Khaldun Waliyuddin Hadhrami,
known as Ibn Khaldun, was born in Tunis 1st Ramadhan 732 H/ 27 Mei 1332 M
from an influential family who emigrated from Seville to Spain. His
descendant came from Yaman who lived in Spain in the beginning of Muslim
administration in 8th century, but after the fall of Seville they move
to Tunisia.[1]
Ibn Khaldun received good education in sharia, logics, philosophy,
Arabic grammar and poetry; all contributing to his capability of a
statesman. No doubt if his role is vital in politics in North Africa and
Spain, where he had an opportunity to write an analysis and valuation
for what was happened. He worked for the ruler of Tunis, Fez, Granada
and Biaja. Finally he worked in Egypt for 24 years in a high level
position, namely as Rais Qadhi (chief judge) of Maliki school and as
lecturer in Al-Azhar University. Political intrigue and jealousy for his
position cause him expelled from high court position for five times.[2]
Ibn Khaldun is known as Father of Social Sciences.[3] In his famous
book, Muqaddima, he writes on dynamics of civilization or umran, which
is considered as foundation of Sociology. However, one can find
foundation of other sciences in the book as well, such as economics [4]
and alchemy. He is considered to complement foundations of alchemy that
was written by Jabir ibn Hayyan through his dialogue with the famous
alchemist Ibn Bishrun, student of Maslamah Al-Majriti, a greatest
alchemist from Spain. [5]
His book Al-Ibar is unique source of historical analysis in his time,
while other work, Tarikh al-Barbar, provides basic introduction in
understanding Arab and Barbar tribes in Maroko, and history of medieval
time.
Ibn Khaldun died in Cairo at 25th Ramadhan 808 AH/ 19th March 1406 AD.
II. CONTRIBUTION IN ECONOMICS
Like other scientist in 14th century, who are usually generalist
(in the sense that their expertise covers many disciplines), Ibn
Khaldun wrote his work by explaining various foundations of science. His
book Muqaddima is written to describe how a civilization (umran)
begins, strengthens and finally falls. For that purpose he elaborates
various constructing elements that finally become its foundation.
However, Ibn Khaldun represents a generation of scholars who wrote
their books using positive-rational approach. This approach diverts from
scholars tradition in previous century, and even centuries afterwards,
which is usually embedded with legal-normative method in their writing.
This uniqueness in approach seemed unpopular in his time since only few
scholars who wrote book using this style, even after some centuries
later. Positive-rational approach might have been extensively used in
science books such as astronomy, medicine and alike but to apply such
new approach in history and sociology was really a new invention.
In economics, Ibn Khaldun’s writing covers almost every foundation of
modern economic thought, ranging from microeconomics to international
trade. It is not a surprise when one finds almost one third of his
Muqaddima consists of socio-economic concepts. He wrote the concepts in
such a way that they are interconnected to one another, that one will
not understand a concept without knowing basic ideas about others. Due
to scope limitation, this paper will only discuss element of
microeconomics (supply, demand and prices) in Ibn Khaldun writing.
1. Labor Theory of Value
According to Ibn Khaldun, labor is source of value. He explains in
details about his theory of labor value and presents it for the first
time in the history.[6 ]According to him,
“…everything in the world is purchased with labor.[7] What is purchased with money or other good is purchased by labor, inasmuch as gained by labor from our body. Money or commodities indeed save us. They contain certain quantity value of labor that we exchange for what it should be, when it contains the same quantity. The value of a commodity for those who own it, and those who do not use it for himself, but exchange it with other commodity, therefore, equal to labor quantity that enable him purchasing or, directing it. Labor, therefore is a real measure of exchangeable value of all commodities.[8]”
“Labor is necessary for revenues and capital accumulation. This is obvious in the case of manufacture (craft). Even if revenue generated from something other than manufacture, the value of generated profit (and capital) should cover labor value by which the commodity is obtained. Without labor, all other things will not be acquired.”
“…everything in the world is purchased with labor.[7] What is purchased with money or other good is purchased by labor, inasmuch as gained by labor from our body. Money or commodities indeed save us. They contain certain quantity value of labor that we exchange for what it should be, when it contains the same quantity. The value of a commodity for those who own it, and those who do not use it for himself, but exchange it with other commodity, therefore, equal to labor quantity that enable him purchasing or, directing it. Labor, therefore is a real measure of exchangeable value of all commodities.[8]”
“Labor is necessary for revenues and capital accumulation. This is obvious in the case of manufacture (craft). Even if revenue generated from something other than manufacture, the value of generated profit (and capital) should cover labor value by which the commodity is obtained. Without labor, all other things will not be acquired.”
Khaldun divides all revenues into two categories: ribh (gross revenue) and kasb (life revenue). Ribh
is secured when man works for himself and sells his product to others.
In this context the value should contain cost of raw material and
natural resources. Kasb is achieved when man works for himself.
Therefore ribh means profit or gross revenue, depending on the context.
In this instance, ribh means gross revenue because raw material cost and
natural resources are included in selling price of an object.
Whether ribh or kasb, revenue is the value realized from man’s labor
i.e. all that is obtained through human effort. According to Ibn
Khaldun, although commodity value comprises of cost from raw material
and natural resources, it is through labor that value become increasing
and hence, wealth grows. Without man’s effort, the opposite will occur.
Ibn Khaldun underlines the role of extra effort that later known as
marginal productivity, in the welfare of a society. His theory on labor
give the reason for the increase of cities, such as one indicated by his
historical analysis, that becomes major element of civilization.
If we can interprete Ibn Khaldun’s idea on work, it is clear that labor
is necessary and sufficient condition for revenue and natural resources
is only necessary condition. Labor and effort tend to produce which in
turn will be used against an exchange through barter, or through the use
of money, namely gold and silver. The process hence generates revenue
and profit that is acquired by man from a manufacture/commodity as value
of his labor, after deducting cost of raw material. Ibn Khaldun also
explains causes of different labor revenue.[10] They might be caused by
different in skill, market size, location, expertise (craftsmanship) or
work, and in how far the authority and governors purchase final
products. When a certain kind of labor become more expensive, namely if
the demand exceeds available supply, the revenue must increase.
High return in a manufacture will attract other players. This is a
dynamic phenomenon that finally increase available supply, and bring to
lower profit. This principle explains how original Ibn Khaldun idea was,
in adjusting long term of the labor, and between certain profession and
others.[11]
Ibn Khaldun precisely observes how income may differ in one place to
another, even for similar profession. Income for judges, crafters even
burglars, for instance, is directly related with welfare level and
living standard in every city, achieved through labor result and
crystallization of productive society. Adam Smith explains the
difference in labor income by comparing between England and Bangladesh,
similar to what Ibn Khaldun did four centuries before, when he compares
income in Fez and Tlemcen.[12] It is Ibn Khaldun, not Adam Smith who
presents, for the first time, labor contribution as wealth creation for a
nation, by stating that labor increases productivity, and that product
exchange in a large market is the prime reason of wealth (and
prosperity) of a nation. On the contrary, decrease in productivity may
lead to decrease in economy and income of its society. In his words, “a civilization generates large profit (income) due to large number of labor force that is the cause of profit.”[13]
A large market means consisting a high demand (D1) compared to
small market. (D0) even in different price level. This also causes large
investment, causing high supply (S1). Through cost and return function,
a large market generate large income as well.
Source: Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics
Source: Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics
It is Ibn Khaldun, who asserts on the need of free economy and free choice. Quoted from his Muqaddima,
Among suppressive action, and very perilous measure to the people
is to compel someone to do forced work injustice. Because labor is a
commodity, like the one we will show later, in income and profit,
representing work value of its recipient… unfortunately most people do
not have income source other than his own labor. Therefore, if they are
forced to work for what they achieved through training, or compelled to
do work in their own field, they will lose the result of their work, and
pulled out of the greatest part of, even all, their income. [14]
To maximize revenue and utility level, man should be free to do what is led by their talent and ability. Through natural talent and learnt ability man can freely produce high quality objects, and often more work-unit per hour.
To maximize revenue and utility level, man should be free to do what is led by their talent and ability. Through natural talent and learnt ability man can freely produce high quality objects, and often more work-unit per hour.
2. Demand, Supply, Price and Profit.
Other original contribution to economics of labor is that Ibn Khaldun
introduces and analyses the relationship of some economic instrument
analysis such as demand, supply, price and profit
a. Demand
Demand for a commodity is based on utility to gain it, and not always
based on the need for it. Hence satisfaction is the motive behind the
demand. It creates incentive for a customer to purchase in market. Ibn
Khaldun therefore planted the firs seed of demand theory that later on
developed by Thomas Robert Malthus, Alfred Marshall, John Hicks and
others. If a commodity demanded attract more customer purchase, either
price or quantity sold will increase. On the other hand, if the demand
for manufacture (craft) decreases, the sale will goes down and therefore
the price will decrease.
Demand for certain commodities depends also on how far they will be
purchased by state. Sultan (king) and ruling elite buy more quantity
than the people can buy individually. A manufacture develops when state
purchase its products. By his analytical and genius thinking, Ibn
Khaldun has found a concept that is known in modern economic literature
as “derived demand”. He said: “Manufacture increases and goes up when
demand for its products increases.” Demand for a manufacture worker is
also derived from the demand for this product in the market.
b. Supply theory
As generally accepted, modern price theory states that cost is the
backbone of supply theory. It is Ibn Khaldun who for the first time
explores analytically the role of production cost in supply and price.
In searching differences between food price produced in fertile land and
the less fertile one, he finds the difference among others merely in
production cost.
In coast and hill areas, where the land is not suitable for
agriculture, the inhabitants are forced to uplift the area condition and
its plantation. They undertook it by giving additional work and things
that need cost. All of them increases cost in agriculture product, which
they include them in determining its sale price. And since then
Andalusia is known for the high price…Its position is in opposite with
land of Berber. Their land is very rich and fertile so that they do not
need to add any cost in agriculture; therefore in that country the food
price become low. [15]
Besides personal and state demand, and production cost, Ibn Khaldun
introduces other factors that influence the cost of commodity or
service, namely (a) welfare and prosperity level of a region, (b) wealth
concentration rate and tax level imposed to intermediaries and traders.
Direct functional relationship between income and consumption provided
by Ibn Khaldun opens the way for consumption function theory as the
cornerstone of Keynesian economics.
c. Profit
Ibn Khaldun also gives original contribution about concept of “profit“.
In economic literature, a theory stating profit as a reward for
uncertainty risk in the future generally refers to Frank Knight, who
published his idea in 1921. Undoubtedly it is Frank Knight who
substantially forwards a profit theory in a well established form.
However, it is Ibn Khaldun, not Knight, who put the cornerstone of this
theory.
Business (commerce) means to buy commodities, store them and wait
for a market fluctuation brings about an increase in price (of these
commodities). This is called “ribh” (profit).[16]
In other context Ibn Khaldun states again the same thought: The clever and experienced people in the city know that to hoard and wait for high price is not good, and its profit can reduce or lost through this hoarding.[17]
The concept of profit hence becomes a reward for facing a risk. In undertaking uncertainty in the future, one who bears the risk may lose instead profit. Similarly, profit or loss may occur as a result of speculation by profit seekers in the market.
In other context Ibn Khaldun states again the same thought: The clever and experienced people in the city know that to hoard and wait for high price is not good, and its profit can reduce or lost through this hoarding.[17]
The concept of profit hence becomes a reward for facing a risk. In undertaking uncertainty in the future, one who bears the risk may lose instead profit. Similarly, profit or loss may occur as a result of speculation by profit seekers in the market.
To maximize profit, Ibn Khaldun introduces magical word of traders: “Buy low and sell high.” [18]
d. Price
If Ibn Khaldun’s magical word is applied in cost analysis, it will be
clear that profit may increase, even for a price of final product, when
someone reduces raw material and other input used in production. It can
be done by the means of purchasing them with discount -or in general- at
low price even from distant market, as indicated in his explanation
about benefit of foreign trade. However, Ibn Khaldun concludes that both
excessive low price and excessive high price will potentially destroy
the market.
Therefore, it is advised to a country not to bring prices artificially
low through subsidy or other method of intervention. Such a policy is
economically perilous because low price commodities will disappear from
market, and increase disincentive for suppliers to produce whenever
their profit is directly affected.
Ibn Khaldun also concludes that excessive high price will not be
appropriate with market expansion. When high-price commodities are few
in the market, high price policy becomes counterproductive and damage
goods flow in the market. Ibn Khaldun hence put the basis of thought
that afterward lead to formulation of disequilibrium analysis. He also
mentions some factors that influence the increase in general price
level, such as increase in demand, supply limitation and increase in
production cost that includes sale tax as one component of total cost.
After his analysis about what creates overall demand in a growing economy, Ibn Khaldun states the following:
After his analysis about what creates overall demand in a growing economy, Ibn Khaldun states the following:
Because demand for luxury goods finally becomes habits and then
becomes necessity. In addition, all labor become expensive in the city,
convenience becomes expensive because there exist many purpose that also
become demand of luxury, and also because the government impose tax in
the market and business transaction. This is reflected in sale price.
Convenience tools, food and labor hence become expensive. As a result,
expenditure increase drastically, proportionate to the culture (city). A
big sum of money is spent. In this situation, people need big amount of
money to acquire necessities for themselves and their family, and other
need as well. [19]
And he therefore concludes: When goods are less, its price increases.
And he therefore concludes: When goods are less, its price increases.
By reading carefully both quotations above, it is clear that Ibn
Khaldun finds what is known now as cost-push inflation and demand pull
inflation (see Box 4 for comparison). In fact, he is the first
philosopher in the history who systematically identifies factors that
influence both commodity price and general price level.
e. Role of Government in State’s Economy
What make Ibn Khaldun differs from his western successor, especially
Classicalist writer is that Ibn Khaldun believes that government plays a
critical role in the economy.
Government plays important role in growth and in country’s economy in general through the purchase of goods and services through fiscal policy, namely tax and expenditure. Government may also provide an incentive environment for work and prosperity, or the opposite, an oppressive system that finally become self-defeating. Although Ibn Khaldun considers government as inefficient (too many calculation is done by those what is called today as cost and benefit) they still play important role in country’s economy through purchase in big scale. Government expenditure stimulates economy using income that increases through multiplier effect. However if Sultan (king, government) accumulates income from tax, business becomes slow and country’s economic activities will be affected significantly through multiplier effect.[20] In addition, welfare program to reduce poverty, help widows, orphans and blinds should be launched (if not become heavy burden to state treasury). Government should spend its tax income wisely to raise their condition in order to maintain their rights and save them from danger.[21]
Government plays important role in growth and in country’s economy in general through the purchase of goods and services through fiscal policy, namely tax and expenditure. Government may also provide an incentive environment for work and prosperity, or the opposite, an oppressive system that finally become self-defeating. Although Ibn Khaldun considers government as inefficient (too many calculation is done by those what is called today as cost and benefit) they still play important role in country’s economy through purchase in big scale. Government expenditure stimulates economy using income that increases through multiplier effect. However if Sultan (king, government) accumulates income from tax, business becomes slow and country’s economic activities will be affected significantly through multiplier effect.[20] In addition, welfare program to reduce poverty, help widows, orphans and blinds should be launched (if not become heavy burden to state treasury). Government should spend its tax income wisely to raise their condition in order to maintain their rights and save them from danger.[21]
f. Macroeconomy and Theory on Money
In macroeconomics, Ibn Khaldun also gives contribution in theory of
money. According to him, money is not the real form of wealth, but an
instrument where the wealth may be obtained. He is the first writer who
present prime function of money as measure of value, store of value and
numerairie.
Mines, gold and silver as (measure of) value for capital
formation…considered as wealth and property. Even in a certain
situation, everything is obtained, the final purpose only to acquire
them. Everything depends on the fluctuation from which (gold and silver)
are exempted. They are basis for profit, property and wealth.[22]
The real form of wealth is not money. The wealth is created or transformed through labor in the form of capital formation in the real measure. Hence it is Ibn Khaldun who the first time differentiate between money and real wealth; although he realizes that the later is obtained by the former. However, money plays more efficient role than barter in business transaction in a society, where man exchanges to each other the result of his labor, both in the form of goods and services, to fulfill the need that cannot be fulfilled individually. Money can also facilitate goods flowing from one market to other, even across the country’s border.
The real form of wealth is not money. The wealth is created or transformed through labor in the form of capital formation in the real measure. Hence it is Ibn Khaldun who the first time differentiate between money and real wealth; although he realizes that the later is obtained by the former. However, money plays more efficient role than barter in business transaction in a society, where man exchanges to each other the result of his labor, both in the form of goods and services, to fulfill the need that cannot be fulfilled individually. Money can also facilitate goods flowing from one market to other, even across the country’s border.
III. CRITICISM TO IBN KHALDUN
Criticism to Ibn Khaldun comes from modern Islamic economic thinker,
among other, Masudul Alam Choudury.[23] In analyzing political economic
thought in Islamic perspective in classical Islamic literature,
Choudhury compares Ibn Khaldun, AlGhazali, Ibn Taimiyya and Shah
Waliyullah Dahlawi. According to him, Ibn Khaldun
….. had equally failed to present a Quranic philosophy of history to
show the rise and decline of civilizations owes to the primal condition
of the believers' commitment or otherwise to the observance of Shari'a
and Sunna Allah in the midst of society and self. These were the
undertakings of Al-Ghazzali and Ibn Taimiyya. Hence, no philosophy of
history could be afforded by Ibn Khaldun. He thus remained to be merely
an empiricist without the greater depth of epistemological-analytical
vision that sways permanence of historical explanation. In the Western
world, we find this attempt being made for Occidentalism by Hegel. In
the Islamic world, a better and deeper study of the philosophy of
history was given by Shah Waliullah.
According to Choudhury, only empirical theory of political economy, not
Islamic political economic theory, that can be derived from Ibn
Khaldun’s book, Muqaddima. Hence for those who believe in the
reductionist philosophy of rationalism as the controller of destinies,
and for those who treat the Divine Reality as outside the determining
life of history as an endogenous force, will continue to take stock of
Ibn Khaldun's work. Thus has Ibn Khaldun become popular in the West
today, but not so Shah Waliullah, Imam Ghazzali and Ibn Taimiyya. That
is because, Ibn Khaldun championed his Greek leanage along with the
Hellenic philosophers like, Ibn Sina, Ibn Rushd, Razi and others. That
was the fashion of intellectual of the time when Ibn Khaldun wrote and
it was the very kind of inquiry that gained the privileges with the
elites and rulers of the time.[24]
Choudhury himself concedes that,
It is true that Ibn Khaldun thought of the pure economic functions
of urban life -- division of labour, economic development and public
finance -- long before Adam Smith and Keynes. He also argues that the
transition from the state of dynasty to the state of towns and cities is
a costly one, but he also promotes the importance of government
functions. From Ibn Taimiyya to Ibn Khaldun, the importance of
government in the economy has increased albeit not without cost.
However, Choudhury does not agree with development transformation of society with excessive role of government. Consequently, the capitalistic and elitist tend will arise in the society who lost their freedom to the state.
However, Choudhury does not agree with development transformation of society with excessive role of government. Consequently, the capitalistic and elitist tend will arise in the society who lost their freedom to the state.
Ibn Khaldun's taxes for the state have become increasingly onerous.
In the above paragraphs, he is in a way defending the taxing powers of
the state in spite of the costs that he recognizes in this state
function. Thus, what can be concluded from these is the seemingly costly
processes involved in the recommended transitions from basic needs
regimes of development to industrial states of development with great
degree of government presence in this transformation.[25]
It has taken off the human freedom to participate in development and has individuals have lost it to the overweening states. If Ibn Khaldun's ideas are taken first, as a prescription of development, it is a socially and economically costly way to develop in the face of capitalistic and elitist claim over the resources of development, ownership and empowerment of elitism. kings and rulers. This sorrowfully has happened in the Arab world contrary to the Islamic precepts of governance.[26]
It has taken off the human freedom to participate in development and has individuals have lost it to the overweening states. If Ibn Khaldun's ideas are taken first, as a prescription of development, it is a socially and economically costly way to develop in the face of capitalistic and elitist claim over the resources of development, ownership and empowerment of elitism. kings and rulers. This sorrowfully has happened in the Arab world contrary to the Islamic precepts of governance.[26]
Finally, Choudhury sees that the idea of development model by Ibn
Khaldun leads to disequilibrium, and contrary to Islamic methodology on
development of socio-economy, political economy and history.
….if Ibn Khaldun's ideas are taken as dynamics of the historical
process of change, there is no relevance in all of these of the Islamic
view to development, wealth and progress, growth and industrial advance
while keeping the moral precepts in tact as was delineated by Ibn
Taimiyya and Imam Ghazzali. Likewise, while the great Shari'a scholars
described their politico-economic universe in the midst of equilibrium,
Ibn Khaldun described it in terms of a disequilibrium dynamics. Economic
development as an evolutionary process leading to the destruction of
dynasties and the rise of cities and nation states as costly entities,
means that this inevitable development must be increasingly costly in
Ibn Khaldun's framework of political economy. Taken in this perspective,
Ibn Khaldun's prescription and message of history are both contrary to
the essentially Islamic methodology of socioeconomic development,
political economy and historicism.[27]
From this criticism it appears that Choudhury tries to understand Ibn Khaldun as an intellectual who is separated from spirit of Islamic epistemology, something that actually may become perilous. This can be understood if the ideas in Ibn Khaldun’s work are not viewed in a unified concept. It is undenied that a large part of Ibn Khaldun’s writing in Muqaddima contains empirical explanation on contemporary phenomena that goes on around him in his age. It is because Ibn Khaldun’s career path walked in the midst of political situations, which contain dynamic intrigues and interests of different rulers. However, to place Ibn Khaldun as an intellectual who does not have any methodology that leads to Islamic epistemology is clearly a misconception. Furthermore, it should be noted that Choudhury‘s criticism is merely based on Muqaddima (translated by Franz Rosenthal), a book written by Ibn Khaldun as introduction to a planned bigger book called Kitab al-Ibar.
A small part of the book has been written and never been completed
aftermath, because of his death. Choudhury seems ignore some details
that may cause his criticism unnecessary. When discussing political
decision-making, for instance, Ibn Khaldun clearly refers to Wilaya
al-‘Ahd that is practiced during Prophet Muhammad’s companions era (Part
III, Chapter 30); and the role of government head in religious matter
(Chapter 31); also his dislike toward the replacement caliph institution
to kingdom (Chapter 28) or his appreciation to the letter of Tahir bin
Husein (Chapter 51) –a senior minister in Abbasid era who is also a
literalist, philosopher and brave man- to his son on a method to manage a
government so as to be the way toward the pleasure of Allah. Ibn
Khaldun’s fond of this letter made him quotes fully in his Muqaddima.
Similar misconception is found in Ibn Khaldun’s socio-economic
analysis. Choudhury is trapped with Western intellectual analysis that
confines Ibn Khaldun on empiricism without examining details given him
to lead them to Islamic perspective. In discussing monopoly (Ihtikar,
Part IV, Chapter 13) for instance, can be seen how Ibn Khaldun explain
it according to sharia and from psychological perspective, or his
criticism against the ruler who applies pricing regulation policy,
quoting Quranic verse 58 of Sura Azzariyat (Part IV, chapter 15). With
this verse, Ibn Khaldun seems suggesting to the ruler that price
regulation will have negative effect for development of their society
and that the policy is against Islamic aqida (ideology, theology).
Beside that, like other Islamic scholars and intellectuals in term of
ethics (akhlaq) Ibn Khaldun always ends his writing by reminding the
reader that there is He Who knows more than everyone in this world.
It is then can be concluded that Choudhury has a fractional view on Ibn
Khaldun, namely form merely empirical approach. He may not realized
that what Ibn Khaldun has done is to explain scientifically what is
already laid by the Almighty in the dynamics of human civilization, from
the perspective of power, socio-economy and knowledge. Furthermore, Ibn
Khaldun wants to teach his Muslim brother an important lesson that to
achieve a success in the world (and the hereafter) a nation cannot
ignore Sunnatullah through empirical description. If a nation deviates
from it, then the disaster will be the logical consequence.
Wallahu A’lam
Allah knows the best
__________
1 AbulHasan M. Sadeq & Aidit Ghazali, Readings in Islamic Economic
Thought, Longman Malaysia, 1992,page 222; Hamed A. Ead, Alchemy in Ibn
Khaldun’s Muqaddima, http://www.frcu.eun.eg/www/universities/html/hamed2.htm
2 Hamed A.Ead, ibid
3 Jan Marie Fritz, The Development of the Field of Clinical Sociology, http://digilander.iol.it/cp47/clnica/fritz.html
4 Ibrahim M. Oweiss, Ibn Khaldun, the Father of Economics, http://www.georgetown.edu/oweiss/ibn.htm ; About Ibn Khaldun’s contribution in Education, see Fahri Kayadibi, Ibn Khaldun and Education, in Fahri Kayadibi, Ibn Khaldun and Education, http://www.renaissance.com.pk/novrefl2yl.html
5 Hamid A. Ead, ibid
6 He never mentions it as a theory, but adeptly presents it in his analysis on workers and their work
7 This preposition is quoted by David Hume in His Political Discourse, published in 1752
8 This quotation is even used by Adam Smith as a footnote. See Ibrahim M. Oweiss, ibid
9 Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics, McMillan, London, 1979
10 It means long time before Ricardo publish his The Principle of Political Economy and Taxation in 1817
11 This concept is challenged by Keynes by his famous expression “in the long term we are dead”. However, Ibn Khaldun’s analysis is not only proved historically correct, but also creates the core thought of classical economist.
12 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, tahqiq by Darwish AlJuwaidy, Maktaba Mishriyyah, Beirut, Part IV Chapter 11, p. 334
13 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part 4 Chapter 14, p. 339
14 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part 4 Chapter 43, p. 264
15 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part IV, Chapter 12, p. 337
16 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 14, p. 366
17 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 13, p. 368
18 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 9, p.366. In his translation, Franz Rosenthal states in its footnote: in 1952 a book written by Frank V. Fischer appears, titled Buy Low, Sell High: Guidance for Readers in Good Investment Method and Wise Trade Technique.
19 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part IV, Chapter 13, p. 338.
20 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part III, Chapter 40, p.257
21 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part III, Chapter 51, p.285
22 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 1, p. 354
23 M.A.Choudhry, A History of Islamic Political Economy thought Among Early Writers; Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406), in http://islamic-finance.net/islamic-economy/chap14/chap14-6.html
24 ibid
25 ibid.
26 ibid.
27 ibid.
2 Hamed A.Ead, ibid
3 Jan Marie Fritz, The Development of the Field of Clinical Sociology, http://digilander.iol.it/cp47/clnica/fritz.html
4 Ibrahim M. Oweiss, Ibn Khaldun, the Father of Economics, http://www.georgetown.edu/oweiss/ibn.htm ; About Ibn Khaldun’s contribution in Education, see Fahri Kayadibi, Ibn Khaldun and Education, in Fahri Kayadibi, Ibn Khaldun and Education, http://www.renaissance.com.pk/novrefl2yl.html
5 Hamid A. Ead, ibid
6 He never mentions it as a theory, but adeptly presents it in his analysis on workers and their work
7 This preposition is quoted by David Hume in His Political Discourse, published in 1752
8 This quotation is even used by Adam Smith as a footnote. See Ibrahim M. Oweiss, ibid
9 Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics, McMillan, London, 1979
10 It means long time before Ricardo publish his The Principle of Political Economy and Taxation in 1817
11 This concept is challenged by Keynes by his famous expression “in the long term we are dead”. However, Ibn Khaldun’s analysis is not only proved historically correct, but also creates the core thought of classical economist.
12 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, tahqiq by Darwish AlJuwaidy, Maktaba Mishriyyah, Beirut, Part IV Chapter 11, p. 334
13 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part 4 Chapter 14, p. 339
14 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part 4 Chapter 43, p. 264
15 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part IV, Chapter 12, p. 337
16 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 14, p. 366
17 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 13, p. 368
18 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 9, p.366. In his translation, Franz Rosenthal states in its footnote: in 1952 a book written by Frank V. Fischer appears, titled Buy Low, Sell High: Guidance for Readers in Good Investment Method and Wise Trade Technique.
19 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part IV, Chapter 13, p. 338.
20 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part III, Chapter 40, p.257
21 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part III, Chapter 51, p.285
22 Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, Part V, Chapter 1, p. 354
23 M.A.Choudhry, A History of Islamic Political Economy thought Among Early Writers; Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406), in http://islamic-finance.net/islamic-economy/chap14/chap14-6.html
24 ibid
25 ibid.
26 ibid.
27 ibid.
REFERENCE
1. A. Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics, Mcmillan, London, 1979.
2. A. Zahoor, Ibn Khaldun (1332-1395 C.E), in http://salam.muslimonline.com/~azahoor/khaldun.html
3. Abd ar-Rahman bin Muhammad bin Khaldun (IBN KHALDUN), in http://faculty-staff.ou.edu/R/F.J.Ragep-1/ibn%20khaldun.htm
4. AbulHasan M. Sadeq & Aidit Ghazali, Readings in Islamic Economic Thought, Longman Malaysia, 1992
5. Fahri Kayadibi, Ibn Khaldun and Education, in http://www.renaissance.com.pk/novrefl2yl.html
6. Hamed A. Ead, Alchemy in Ibn Khaldun’s Muqaddima, in http://www.frcu.eun.eg/www/universities/html/hamed2.htm
7. Ibn Khaldun (1332-1395 C.E) in http://www/ummah.org.uk/history/scholars/KHALDUN.html
8. Ibn Khaldun (1332-1395 C.E), in http://www.geocities.com/abu_gurnah/ibnkhaldun.html
9. Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, tahqiq by Darwisy AlJuwaidy, Maktabah Mishriyyah, Beirut
10. Ibrahim M. Oweiss, Ibn Khaldun, the Father of Economics, in http://www.georgetown.edu/oweiss/ibn.htm
11. Imad A. Ahmad, An Islamic Perspective on the Wealth of Nations, in http://www.minaret.org/malaysia.htm
12. James Kalb, Ibn Khaldun and Our Age, in http://counterrevolution.net/kalb_texts/khaldun.html#16
13. Jan Marie Fritz, The Development of the Field of Clinical Sociology, in http://digilander.iol.it/cp47/clnica/fritz.html
14. M.A.Choudhry, A History of Islamic Political Economy thought Among Early Writers Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406), in http://islamic-finance.net/islamic-economy/chap14/chap14-6.html
15. Mark Lovewell, Rise and Fall: Ibn Khaldun and the Effects of Taxation, in Understanding Economics, A Contemporary Perspective, http://www.ryerson.ca/~lovewell/khaldun.html
16. Maverick F. Fisher, Ibn Khaldun’s Civil Society, in http://www.la.utexas.edu/chenry/civil/archives95/csspapers/0017.html
17. Michael P. Todaro, Economic Development in the Thirld World, Longman, New York, 4th edition, 1989
18. Paul A. Samuelson and William Nordhaus, Macroeconomics, McGraw-Hill, New York, 12th edition, 1985.
19. Rudiger Dornbusch & Stanley Fisher, Macroeconomics, McGraw-Hill, New York, 4th edition, 1987.
20. William H. Branson, Macroeconomic Theory and Practice, Harper & Row, New York, 3rd edition, 1989.
1. A. Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics, Mcmillan, London, 1979.
2. A. Zahoor, Ibn Khaldun (1332-1395 C.E), in http://salam.muslimonline.com/~azahoor/khaldun.html
3. Abd ar-Rahman bin Muhammad bin Khaldun (IBN KHALDUN), in http://faculty-staff.ou.edu/R/F.J.Ragep-1/ibn%20khaldun.htm
4. AbulHasan M. Sadeq & Aidit Ghazali, Readings in Islamic Economic Thought, Longman Malaysia, 1992
5. Fahri Kayadibi, Ibn Khaldun and Education, in http://www.renaissance.com.pk/novrefl2yl.html
6. Hamed A. Ead, Alchemy in Ibn Khaldun’s Muqaddima, in http://www.frcu.eun.eg/www/universities/html/hamed2.htm
7. Ibn Khaldun (1332-1395 C.E) in http://www/ummah.org.uk/history/scholars/KHALDUN.html
8. Ibn Khaldun (1332-1395 C.E), in http://www.geocities.com/abu_gurnah/ibnkhaldun.html
9. Ibn Khaldun, Muqaddima, tahqiq by Darwisy AlJuwaidy, Maktabah Mishriyyah, Beirut
10. Ibrahim M. Oweiss, Ibn Khaldun, the Father of Economics, in http://www.georgetown.edu/oweiss/ibn.htm
11. Imad A. Ahmad, An Islamic Perspective on the Wealth of Nations, in http://www.minaret.org/malaysia.htm
12. James Kalb, Ibn Khaldun and Our Age, in http://counterrevolution.net/kalb_texts/khaldun.html#16
13. Jan Marie Fritz, The Development of the Field of Clinical Sociology, in http://digilander.iol.it/cp47/clnica/fritz.html
14. M.A.Choudhry, A History of Islamic Political Economy thought Among Early Writers Ibn Khaldun (1332-1406), in http://islamic-finance.net/islamic-economy/chap14/chap14-6.html
15. Mark Lovewell, Rise and Fall: Ibn Khaldun and the Effects of Taxation, in Understanding Economics, A Contemporary Perspective, http://www.ryerson.ca/~lovewell/khaldun.html
16. Maverick F. Fisher, Ibn Khaldun’s Civil Society, in http://www.la.utexas.edu/chenry/civil/archives95/csspapers/0017.html
17. Michael P. Todaro, Economic Development in the Thirld World, Longman, New York, 4th edition, 1989
18. Paul A. Samuelson and William Nordhaus, Macroeconomics, McGraw-Hill, New York, 12th edition, 1985.
19. Rudiger Dornbusch & Stanley Fisher, Macroeconomics, McGraw-Hill, New York, 4th edition, 1987.
20. William H. Branson, Macroeconomic Theory and Practice, Harper & Row, New York, 3rd edition, 1989.
∗ Opinion in this paper does not represent the view of the institution where the writer works.
paper presented at International Conference on Ibn Khaldun held in Madrid, Spain on November 3-5, 2006
also published by www.muslimheritage.org/topics/default.cfm?ArticleID=1210 and http://www.uned.es/congreso-ibn-khaldun/ponencia.htm
No comments:
Post a Comment